Main Content
Lesson 2: Principles of Public Finance - The Role of Government
Economic Efficiency Criteria
The previous description of market failures provides some general insights into why it might not be wise to rely entirely on the private sector to provide goods and services in an economy. However, it is important to realize that a decision to involve the public sector in the provision of a particular good or service does not necessarily mean that society will be better-off. For example, it is possible to conceive of a situation in which the construction of a public road or bridge will result in costs to society that far exceed the benefits the project will generate.
This would be the case if a decision was made to build a bridge or a road that no one ends up using. Consequently, it is important to know not only whether a good or service ought to be provided by the public sector, but also whether it makes sense from an economic perspective to provide it. On this page we introduce two additional public finance concepts that shed light on the latter question (i.e., whether the provision of a particular type of public good or service will enhance economic welfare): Pareto efficiency criterion, and Kaldor-Hicks efficiency criterion
As indicated by their names, these concepts relate to economic efficiency. Briefly described, economic efficiency deals with how well a society economizes with (i.e., uses) its limited resources. Formally, economic efficiency is achieved when a society's resources are used or allocated in a way so that there is no other possible way for a society to use them better.
The second criterion, the Kaldor-Hicks efficiency criterion, named for economists Nicholas Kaldor and John Hicks, captures some of the intuitive appeal of the Pareto efficiency criterion, but is applicable to more circumstances. It states that a good or a service should be provided if a Pareto optimal outcome can be reached by arranging sufficient compensation from those who are made better-off to those who are made worse-off. In this manner, everyone would end up no worse-off than before. More simply put, a good or service should be provided as long as the total (aggregate) benefits of the project outweigh the total costs. If this is the case, the provision of the good or service will increase societal welfare and society as a whole will be better off.
A major challenge associated with the Pareto and the Kaldor-Hicks criteria is that they both assume that it is possible to assess the value that individuals in a community place on a particular project, public good, or service that is being considered. In the absence of market prices, assessing the value that different people place on a particular good or service is very difficult. Nevertheless, economists and analysts often attempt to estimate these values so that they can determine the total benefits (i.e., the aggregate benefits for all individuals in a community) that will result from producing a particular public good or service. As will be discussed in Lesson 6, they do this by applying a variety of techniques aimed at determining the perceived benefits to each individual and then expressing them in dollar terms. The aggregate value of all the individual perceived benefits are then compared with the aggregate costs. If the benefits exceed the costs, the Kaldor-Hicks criterion is met.
A simple illustration of the Kaldor-Hicks criteria would be if 10 individuals who live on a particular street decide to invest in a street light. Let's say that each of five of the individuals perceives the value (i.e., what they are willing to contribute in dollars) of the light to be $500. That is, they would be willing to pay $500 each for this good if it were sold on the private market. Furthermore, let's say that four of the individuals perceive the value to be $400, and the remaining individual perceives it to be $100. In this example, the Kaldor-Hicks criterion would be met as long as the total cost of the street light were less than $4,200, which is the total value of the perceived benefits: ($500 x 5) + ($400 x 4) + ($100 x 1). For example, if the cost were $3,200, the net benefit to society would be $1,000.
Review Exercise: Efficiency Criteria
The review exercise below provides an additional illustration of the above criteria. Try to answer the questions before you click to retrieve the correct answers.
A planned community project (a public good) will cost $2,500 to produce. It has been determined that it will be financed by a one-time fee of $500 that is evenly distributed across the community members. If undertaken, the project will benefit the five members of the community as follows:
Resident | Individual Benefit | Cost Share |
---|---|---|
A | $800 | $500 |
B | $800 | $500 |
C | $300 | $500 |
D | $350 | $500 |
E | $450 | $500 |
Kaldor-Hicks: Ethical Dilemma
As noted above, the Kaldor-Hicks criterion is more easily applied to practical circumstances. However, an obvious drawback to the Kaldor-Hicks efficiency criterion is that someone might be left worse-off if public resources were allocated or used in a particular way. As such, it gives rise to a range of possible ethical and moral dilemmas. An illustration of this is provided in the required Robert Caro (1998) article (you may download this article from the Library Reserves). The article describes some of the ethical and moral trade-offs that occurred when Robert Moses designed and implemented the New York City park and transportation system.
- What groups of people appear to have been made worse-off in the case described?
- Under what circumstances (if any) is it justifiable to provide a particular good or service that will increase the overall well-being of an economic region, but harm a few?